October 19, 2014 2:33 pm
Eurozone stagnation is a greater threat than debt
Wolfgang Munchau / Financial Times / http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/326b0cec-5560-11e4-89e8-00144feab7de.html?siteedition=intl#ixzz3GclFkjT9
Monetary policy can boost markets in the
shortrun, but this cannot be sustained indefinitely
It would be wrong to think last week’s
global market gyrations signal a return of the eurozone debt crisis. Sovereign
bond spreads in the eurozone did not move by much, except in Greece .
What happened last week is something rather
different. Financial markets have woken up to the possibility of a
eurozone-wide economic depression with very low inflation over the next 10 to
20 years. This is what the fall in various measures of inflation expectations
tells us. Investors are not worried about the solvency of a member state. That
was clearly different two years ago.
But the present scenario is no less
disturbing. The implications for those who live in such an economic snake pit
are already visible: high unemployment; rising poverty; real and nominal wage
stagnation; a debt burden that will not come down in real terms; a decline in
public sector services, and in public investment. A shocking example is the
decrepit state of German military hardware. Of the Luftwaffe’s 254 fighter
planes, 150 cannot fly.
The eurozone’s stagnation will affect the
rest of the world to different degrees. The UK
might manage to escape the same fate, but the eurozone economy is big enough to
pull Britain
down with it. Hardest hit will be the parts of central and eastern Europe that
do not use the euro. They are caught between an imploding Russia and a stagnating Europe .
It is hard to see how the oil price can recover in an environment of
permanently low growth. And it is even harder to see how Russia can live
with a permanently depressed oil price.
Secular stagnation – the idea that a
chronic shortfall of investment might produce a long period of weak demand –
also has disturbing implications for financial investors. The recent high
levels of equity prices were premised on the best possible of all scenarios:
that productivity growth rates would revert to historical averages, and that
the level of gross domestic product would eventually catch up with the
pre-crisis economic growth trajectory. Investors have now begun to realise that
neither is going to happen. GDP is still only close to the levels of 2007;
growth is slow.
The share of GDP accounted for by profits
cannot go much higher, either. So, if productivity growth remains low, it is
hard to see how equity investments can yield large real returns. Monetary
policy can boost markets in the short-run, but this cannot be sustained
indefinitely. In such an environment, the yields on risk free securities will
be low.
With secular stagnation comes a permanent
fall in inflation to levels below the 2 per cent target. The real value of
public and private-sector debt will not therefore come down as fast as it
should. This in turn will make it harder for governments, companies and
individuals to reduce their debt. In such an environment, expect default rates
to be high. German sovereign bonds become the only asset in the eurozone that
investors regard as more or less risk-free.
One would have thought that such a scenario
would produce counteracting forces, for example a weaker exchange rate. Unfortunately,
that is not necessarily true. The eurozone is running a current account surplus
of close to 3 per cent of GDP this year. One would normally expect the currency
of an economy with a persistent current account surplus to be strong. In any
case, the exchange rate matters a lot more for smaller and medium-sized
economies than for large ones such as the US and the eurozone because the
share of trade in GDP tends to be smaller for large economies than for small
ones.
The eurozone is a large semi-closed economy,
trading most of its goods and service internally, in euros. Whatever is going
to save the eurozone, it cannot be the exchange rate, unless the euro
depreciates to an extreme extent.
Secular stagnation is thus a lot more
dramatic than a debt crisis. With such a threat hanging over us, one would have
thought every rational policy maker would want to avoid such a calamity. That
would indeed be the case if the crisis occurred in a normal country. For a
monetary union where policy is not co-ordinated and where policy makers take a
national perspective, the risk of secular stagnation looms large. Even the
European Central Bank, the only actor with a eurozone-wide remit, faces legal
constraints. This may explain its reluctance to go for quantitative easing. Even
as an advocate of QE, I cannot deny we are treading in a legally grey area.
Eurozone policy makers face three choices.
First, they can transform the eurozone into a political union, and do whatever
it takes: a eurobond, a small fiscal union, transfer mechanisms and a banking
union worthy of its name. Second, they can accept secular stagnation. The final
choice is a break-up of the eurozone. The second and third choices are not
mutually exclusive. As the political union is firmly off the table, this leaves
us with a choice between depression and failure – or both in succession.
munchau@eurointelligence.com
Sem comentários:
Enviar um comentário