Capitalism and its
critics
A modern Marx
Thomas Piketty’s
blockbuster book is a great piece of scholarship, but a poor guide to policy
May 3rd 2014 | The Economist / From the
print edition / http://www.economist.com/news/leaders/21601512-thomas-pikettys-blockbuster-book-great-piece-scholarship-poor-guide-policy
WHEN the
first volume of Karl Marx’s “Das Kapital” was published in 1867, it took five
years to sell 1,000 copies in its original German. It was not translated into
English for two decades, and this newspaper did not see fit to mention it until
1907. By comparison, Thomas Piketty’s “Capital in the Twenty-First Century” is
an overnight sensation. Originally published in French (when we first reviewed
it), Mr Piketty’s vast tome on income-and-wealth distribution has become a
bestseller since the English translation appeared in March. In America it is
the top-selling book on Amazon, fiction included.
The book’s
success has a lot to do with being about the right subject at the right time.
Inequality has suddenly become a fevered topic, especially in America . Having
for years dismissed the gaps between the haves and have-nots as a European
obsession, Americans, stung by the excesses of Wall Street, are suddenly
talking about the rich and redistribution. Hence the attraction of a book which
argues that growing wealth concentration is inherent to capitalism and
recommends a global tax on wealth as the progressive solution.
“Capital” has duly enraptured the left,
infuriated the right and spiced up the dismal science in the popular mind (see
article). But if Mr Piketty does set the tone of debate on inequality, the
world will be the poorer for it. For like its 19th-century namesake, “Capital”
contains some marvellous scholarship, but as a guide to action, is deeply
flawed.
“Capital” makes three big contributions in
its 577 pages. First, Mr Piketty, a pioneer in using tax statistics to measure
inequality, painstakingly documents the evolution of income and wealth over the
past 300 years, particularly in Europe and America . In doing so, he shows that
the period from about 1914 to the 1970s was an historical outlier in which both
income inequality and the stock of wealth (relative to annual national income)
fell dramatically. Since the 1970s both wealth and income gaps have been rising
back towards their pre-20th-century norms. There are surely a few snafus in
these statistics, but this work has transformed understanding of the history of
wealth, with eye-popping results. Who knew, for instance, that the annual value
of inheritances in France has tripled from less than 5% of GDP in the 1950s to
about 15%, not all that far from the 19th-century peak of 25%? As a piece of
empirical sleuthing, the book is indisputably brilliant.
Mr Piketty’s second contribution is to come
up with a theory of capitalism that explains these facts and offers a
prediction of where wealth distribution is heading. His central claim is that
the free-market system has a natural tendency towards increasing the
concentration of wealth, because the rate of return on property and investments
has consistently been higher than the rate of economic growth. Two world wars,
the Depression and high taxes pushed down the return on wealth in the 20th
century, while rapid productivity and population rises pushed up growth. But
without such countervailing factors, Mr Piketty argues, higher returns on
capital will concentrate wealth—especially when, as now, an ageing population
means that growth should slow.
Mr Piketty’s expectation of rising wealth
concentration is not outlandish. However, it is a prediction based on
extrapolating from the past, not an inherent model of capitalism. He assumes
that the returns to capital will not fall substantially even as the stock of
wealth rises. That may prove to be true, but the Piketty prediction is a
hypothesis, not an iron law.
Nit-Piketty
That is where the problems start, because
Mr Piketty’s third contribution is to offer policy proposals that assume this
growing concentration of wealth is not only inevitable, but the thing that
matters most. He prescribes a progressive global tax on capital (an annual levy
that could start at 0.1% and hits a maximum of perhaps 10% on the greatest
fortunes). He also suggests a punitive 80% tax rate on incomes above $500,000
or so.
Here “Capital” drifts to the left and loses
credibility. Mr Piketty asserts rather than explains why tempering wealth
concentration should be the priority (as opposed to, say, boosting growth). He
barely acknowledges any trade-offs or costs to his redistributionist agenda.
Most economists, common sense and a lot of French businesspeople would argue
that higher taxes on income and wealth put off entrepreneurs and risk taking;
he blithely dismisses that. And his to-do list is oddly blinkered in its focus
on taxing the rich. He ignores ways to broaden the ownership of capital, from
“baby bonds” to government top-ups of private saving accounts. Some capital
taxes could sit nicely in a sensible 21st-century policy toolkit (inheritance
taxes, in particular), but they are not the only, or even the main, way to
ensure broad-based prosperity.
Sem comentários:
Enviar um comentário