The Economist explains
Thomas Piketty’s “Capital”, summarised in four
paragraphs
May 4th 2014, 23:50 by R.A. / http://www.economist.com/blogs/economist-explains/2014/05/economist-explains
IT
IS the economics book taking the world by storm. "Capital in the
Twenty-First Century", written by the French economist Thomas Piketty, was
published in French last year and in English in March of this year. The English
version quickly became an unlikely bestseller, and it has prompted a broad and
energetic debate on the book’s subject: the outlook for global inequality. Some
reckon it heralds or may itself cause a pronounced shift in the focus of
economic policy, toward distributional questions. This newspaper has hailed Mr
Piketty as "the modern Marx" (Karl, that is). But what’s it all
about?
"Capital" is built on more than a
decade of research by Mr Piketty and a handful of other economists, detailing
historical changes in the concentration of income and wealth. This pile of data
allows Mr Piketty to sketch out the evolution of inequality since the beginning
of the industrial revolution. In the 18th and 19th centuries western European
society was highly unequal. Private wealth dwarfed national income and was
concentrated in the hands of the rich families who sat atop a relatively rigid
class structure. This system persisted even as industrialisation slowly
contributed to rising wages for workers. Only the chaos of the first and second
world wars and the Depression disrupted this pattern. High taxes, inflation,
bankruptcies, and the growth of sprawling welfare states caused wealth to
shrink dramatically, and ushered in a period in which both income and wealth
were distributed in relatively egalitarian fashion. But the shocks of the early
20th century have faded and wealth is now reasserting itself. On many measures,
Mr Piketty reckons, the importance of wealth in modern economies is approaching
levels last seen before the first world war.
From this history, Mr Piketty derives a
grand theory of capital and inequality. As a general rule wealth grows faster
than economic output, he explains, a concept he captures in the expression r
> g (where r is the rate of return to wealth and g is the economic growth rate).
Other things being equal, faster economic growth will diminish the importance
of wealth in a society, whereas slower growth will increase it (and demographic
change that slows global growth will make capital more dominant). But there are
no natural forces pushing against the steady concentration of wealth. Only a
burst of rapid growth (from technological progress or rising population) or
government intervention can be counted on to keep economies from returning to
the “patrimonial capitalism” that worried Karl Marx. Mr Piketty closes the book
by recommending that governments step in now, by adopting a global tax on
wealth, to prevent soaring inequality contributing to economic or political
instability down the road.
The book has unsurprisingly attracted plenty
of criticism. Some wonder whether Mr Piketty is right to think the future will
look like the past. Theory argues that it should become ever harder to earn a
good return on wealth the more there is of it. And today’s super-rich mostly
come by their wealth through work, rather than via inheritance. Others argue
that Mr Piketty’s policy recommendations are more ideologically than
economically driven and could do more harm than good. But many of the sceptics
nonetheless have kind words for the book’s contributions, in terms of data and
analysis. Whether or not Mr Piketty succeeds in changing policy, he will have
influenced the way thousands of readers and plenty of economists think about
these issues.
Sem comentários:
Enviar um comentário