Yanis Varoufakis: How I became an erratic Marxist
Before he entered
politics, Yanis Varoufakis, the iconoclastic Greek finance minister at the
centre of the latest eurozone standoff wrote this searing account of European
capitalism and and how the left can learn from Marx’s mistakes
Yanis Varoufakis
Wednesday 18 February 2015 / GUARDIAN / http://www.theguardian.com/news/2015/feb/18/yanis-varoufakis-how-i-became-an-erratic-marxist
In 2008, capitalism had its second global
spasm. The financial crisis set off a chain reaction that pushed Europe into a downward spiral that continues to this day.
Europe ’s present situation is not merely a
threat for workers, for the dispossessed, for the bankers, for social classes
or, indeed, nations. No, Europe ’s current
posture poses a threat to civilisation as we know it.
If my prognosis is correct, and we are not
facing just another cyclical slump soon to be overcome, the question that
arises for radicals is this: should we welcome this crisis of European
capitalism as an opportunity to replace it with a better system? Or should we
be so worried about it as to embark upon a campaign for stabilising European
capitalism?
To me, the answer is clear. Europe ’s crisis is far less likely to give birth to a
better alternative to capitalism than it is to unleash dangerously regressive
forces that have the capacity to cause a humanitarian bloodbath, while
extinguishing the hope for any progressive moves for generations to come.
For this view I have been accused, by
well-meaning radical voices, of being “defeatist” and of trying to save an
indefensible European socioeconomic system. This criticism, I confess, hurts.
And it hurts because it contains more than a kernel of truth.
I share the view that this European Union
is typified by a large democratic deficit that, in combination with the denial
of the faulty architecture of its monetary union, has put Europe ’s
peoples on a path to permanent recession. And I also bow to the criticism that
I have campaigned on an agenda founded on the assumption that the left was, and
remains, squarely defeated. I confess I would much rather be promoting a
radical agenda, the raison d’être of which is to replace European capitalism
with a different system.
Yet my aim here is instead to offer a
window into my view of a repugnant European capitalism whose implosion, despite
its many ills, should be avoided at all costs. It is a confession intended to
convince radicals that we have a contradictory mission: to arrest the freefall
of European capitalism in order to buy the time we need to formulate its alternative.
Why a Marxist?
When I chose the subject of my doctoral
thesis, back in 1982, I deliberately focused on a highly mathematical topic
within which Marx’s thought was irrelevant. When, later on, I embarked on an
academic career, as a lecturer in mainstream economics departments, the
implicit contract between myself and the departments that offered me
lectureships was that I would be teaching the type of economic theory that left
no room for Marx. In the late 1980s, I was hired by the University of Sydney ’s
school of economics in order to keep out a leftwing candidate (although I did
not know this at the time).
Yanis Varoufakis: ‘Karl Marx was
responsible for framing my perspective of the world we live in, from my
childhood to this day.’ Photograph: PA
Given all this, you may be puzzled to hear
me call myself a Marxist. But, in truth, Karl Marx was responsible for framing
my perspective of the world we live in, from my childhood to this day. This is
not something that I often volunteer to talk about in “polite society” because
the very mention of the M-word switches audiences off. But I never deny it
either. After a few years of addressing audiences with whom I do not share an
ideology, a need has crept up on me to talk about Marx’s imprint on my
thinking. To explain why, while an unapologetic Marxist, I think it is
important to resist him passionately in a variety of ways. To be, in other
words, erratic in one’s Marxism.
If my whole academic career largely ignored
Marx, and my current policy recommendations are impossible to describe as
Marxist, why bring up my Marxism now? The answer is simple: Even my non-Marxist
economics was guided by a mindset influenced by Marx. A radical social theorist
can challenge the economic mainstream in two different ways, I always thought.
One way is by means of immanent criticism. To accept the mainstream’s axioms
and then expose its internal contradictions. To say: “I shall not contest your
assumptions but here is why your own conclusions do not logically flow on from
them.” This was, indeed, Marx’s method of undermining British political
economics. He accepted every axiom by Adam Smith and David Ricardo in order to
demonstrate that, in the context of their assumptions, capitalism was a
contradictory system. The second avenue that a radical theorist can pursue is,
of course, the construction of alternative theories to those of the
establishment, hoping that they will be taken seriously.
My view on this dilemma has always been
that the powers that be are never perturbed by theories that embark from assumptions
different to their own. The only thing that can destabilise and genuinely
challenge mainstream, neoclassical economists is the demonstration of the
internal inconsistency of their own models. It was for this reason that, from
the very beginning, I chose to delve into the guts of neoclassical theory and
to spend next to no energy trying to develop alternative, Marxist models of
capitalism. My reasons, I submit, were quite Marxist.
“When called upon to comment on the world we live in,
I had no alternative but to fall back on Marxist tradition”
When called upon to comment on the world we
live in, I had no alternative but to fall back on the Marxist tradition which
had shaped my thinking ever since my metallurgist father impressed upon me,
when I was still a child, the effect of technological innovation on the
historical process. How, for instance, the passage from the bronze age to the
iron age sped up history; how the discovery of steel greatly accelerated
historical time; and how silicon-based IT technologies are fast-tracking
socioeconomic and historical discontinuities.
My first encounter with Marx’s writings
came very early in life, as a result of the strange times I grew up in, with Greece exiting
the nightmare of the neofascist dictatorship of 1967-74. What caught my eye was
Marx’s mesmerising gift for writing a dramatic script for human history, indeed
for human damnation, that was also laced with the possibility of salvation and
authentic spirituality.
Marx created a narrative populated by
workers, capitalists, officials and scientists who were history’s dramatis
personae. They struggled to harness reason and science in the context of
empowering humanity while, contrary to their intentions, unleashing demonic
forces that usurped and subverted their own freedom and humanity.
This dialectical perspective, where
everything is pregnant with its opposite, and the eager eye with which Marx
discerned the potential for change in what seemed to be the most unchanging of
social structures, helped me to grasp the great contradictions of the
capitalist era. It dissolved the paradox of an age that generated the most
remarkable wealth and, in the same breath, the most conspicuous poverty. Today,
turning to the European crisis, the crisis in the United States and the long-term
stagnation of Japanese capitalism, most commentators fail to appreciate the
dialectical process under their nose. They recognise the mountain of debts and
banking losses but neglect the opposite side of the same coin: the mountain of
idle savings that are “frozen” by fear and thus fail to convert into productive
investments. A Marxist alertness to binary oppositions might have opened their
eyes.
A major reason why established opinion
fails to come to terms with contemporary reality is that it never understood
the dialectically tense “joint production” of debts and surpluses, of growth
and unemployment, of wealth and poverty, indeed of good and evil. Marx’s script
alerted us these binary oppositions as the sources of history’s cunning.
From my first steps of thinking like an
economist, to this very day, it occurred to me that Marx had made a discovery
that must remain at the heart of any useful analysis of capitalism. It was the
discovery of another binary opposition deep within human labour. Between
labour’s two quite different natures: i) labour as a value-creating activity
that can never be quantified in advance (and is therefore impossible to
commodify), and ii) labour as a quantity (eg, numbers of hours worked) that is
for sale and comes at a price. That is what distinguishes labour from other
productive inputs such as electricity: its twin, contradictory, nature. A
differentiation-cum-contradiction that political economics neglected to make
before Marx came along and that mainstream economics is steadfastly refusing to
acknowledge today.
Both electricity and labour can be thought
of as commodities. Indeed, both employers and workers struggle to commodify
labour. Employers use all their ingenuity, and that of their HR management
minions, to quantify, measure and homogenise labour. Meanwhile, prospective
employees go through the wringer in an anxious attempt to commodify their
labour power, to write and rewrite their CVs in order to portray themselves as
purveyors of quantifiable labour units. And there’s the rub. If workers and
employers ever succeed in commodifying labour fully, capitalism will perish.
This is an insight without which capitalism’s tendency to generate crises can
never be fully grasped and, also, an insight that no one has access to without
some exposure to Marx’s thought.
Science fiction becomes documentary
In the classic 1953 film Invasion of the
Body Snatchers, the alien force does not attack us head on, unlike in, say, HG
Wells’s The War of the Worlds. Instead, people are taken over from within,
until nothing is left of their human spirit and emotions. Their bodies are
shells that used to contain a free will and which now labour, go through the
motions of everyday “life”, and function as human simulacra “liberated” from
the unquantifiable essence of human nature. This is something like what would
have transpired if human labour had become perfectly reducible to human capital
and thus fit for insertion into the vulgar economists’ models.
Invasion of the Body Snatchers. Photograph:
SNAP/REX
Every non-Marxist economic theory that
treats human and non-human productive inputs as interchangeable assumes that
the dehumanisation of human labour is complete. But if it could ever be
completed, the result would be the end of capitalism as a system capable of
creating and distributing value. For a start, a society of dehumanised automata
would resemble a mechanical watch full of cogs and springs, each with its own
unique function, together producing a “good”: timekeeping. Yet if that society
contained nothing but other automata, timekeeping would not be a “good”. It
would certainly be an “output” but why a “good”? Without real humans to
experience the clock’s function, there can be no such thing as “good” or “bad”.
If capital ever succeeds in quantifying,
and subsequently fully commodifying, labour, as it is constantly trying to, it
will also squeeze that indeterminate, recalcitrant human freedom from within
labour that allows for the generation of value. Marx’s brilliant insight into
the essence of capitalist crises was precisely this: the greater capitalism’s
success in turning labour into a commodity the less the value of each unit of
output it generates, the lower the profit rate and, ultimately, the nearer the
next recession of the economy as a system. The portrayal of human freedom as an
economic category is unique in Marx, making possible a distinctively dramatic
and analytically astute interpretation of capitalism’s propensity to snatch
recession, even depression, from the jaws of growth.
When Marx was writing that labour is the
living, form-giving fire; the transitoriness of things; their temporality; he
was making the greatest contribution any economist has ever made to our
understanding of the acute contradiction buried inside capitalism’s DNA. When
he portrayed capital as a “… force we must submit to … it develops a
cosmopolitan, universal energy which breaks through every limit and every bond
and posts itself as the only policy, the only universality the only limit and
the only bond”, he was highlighting the reality that labour can be purchased by
liquid capital (ie money), in its commodity form, but that it will always carry
with it a will hostile to the capitalist buyer. But Marx was not just making a psychological,
philosophical or political statement. He was, rather, supplying a remarkable
analysis of why the moment that labour (as an unquantifiable activity) sheds
this hostility, it becomes sterile, incapable of producing value.
At a time when neoliberals have ensnared
the majority in their theoretical tentacles, incessantly regurgitating the
ideology of enhancing labour productivity in an effort to enhance
competitiveness with a view to creating growth etc, Marx’s analysis offers a
powerful antidote. Capital can never win in its struggle to turn labour into an
infinitely elastic, mechanised input, without destroying itself. That is what
neither the neoliberals nor the Keynesians will ever grasp. “If the whole class
of the wage-labourer were to be annihilated by machinery”, wrote Marx “how
terrible that would be for capital, which, without wage-labour, ceases to be
capital!”
What has Marx done for us?
Almost all schools of thought, including
those of some progressive economists, like to pretend that, though Marx was a
powerful figure, very little of his contribution remains relevant today. I beg
to differ. Besides having captured the basic drama of capitalist dynamics, Marx
has given me the tools with which to become immune to the toxic propaganda of neoliberalism.
For example, the idea that wealth is privately produced and then appropriated
by a quasi-illegitimate state, through taxation, is easy to succumb to if one
has not been exposed first to Marx’s poignant argument that precisely the
opposite applies: wealth is collectively produced and then privately
appropriated through social relations of production and property rights that
rely, for their reproduction, almost exclusively on false consciousness.
In his recent book Never Let a Serious
Crisis Go to Waste, the historian of economic thought, Philip Mirowski, has
highlighted the neoliberals’ success in convincing a large array of people that
markets are not just a useful means to an end but also an end in themselves.
According to this view, while collective action and public institutions are
never able to “get it right”, the unfettered operations of decentralised
private interest are guaranteed to produce not only the right outcomes but also
the right desires, character, ethos even. The best example of this form of
neoliberal crassness is, of course, the debate on how to deal with climate
change. Neoliberals have rushed in to argue that, if anything is to be done, it
must take the form of creating a quasi-market for “bads” (eg an emissions
trading scheme), since only markets “know” how to price goods and bads
appropriately. To understand why such a quasi-market solution is bound to fail
and, more importantly, where the motivation comes from for such “solutions”,
one can do much worse than to become acquainted with the logic of capital
accumulation that Marx outlined and the Polish economist Michal Kalecki adapted
to a world ruled by networked oligopolies.
Neoliberals have rushed in with
quasi-market responses to climate change, such as emissions trading schemes.
Photograph: Jon Woo/Reuters
In the 20th century, the two political
movements that sought their roots in Marx’s thought were the communist and
social democratic parties. Both of them, in addition to their other errors
(and, indeed, crimes) failed, to their detriment, to follow Marx’s lead in a
crucial regard: instead of embracing liberty and rationality as their rallying
cries and organising concepts, they opted for equality and justice, bequeathing
the concept of freedom to the neoliberals. Marx was adamant: The problem with
capitalism is not that it is unfair but that it is irrational, as it habitually
condemns whole generations to deprivation and unemployment and even turns
capitalists into angst-ridden automata, living in permanent fear that unless
they commodify their fellow humans fully so as to serve capital accumulation
more efficiently, they will cease to be capitalists. So, if capitalism appears
unjust this is because it enslaves everyone; it wastes human and natural
resources; the same production line that pumps out remarkable gizmos and untold
wealth, also produces deep unhappiness and crises.
Having failed to couch a critique of
capitalism in terms of freedom and rationality, as Marx thought essential,
social democracy and the left in general allowed the neoliberals to usurp the
mantle of freedom and to win a spectacular triumph in the contest of
ideologies.
Perhaps the most significant dimension of
the neoliberal triumph is what has come to be known as the “democratic
deficit”. Rivers of crocodile tears have flowed over the decline of our great
democracies during the past three decades of financialisation and globalisation.
Marx would have laughed long and hard at those who seem surprised, or upset, by
the “democratic deficit”. What was the great objective behind 19th-century
liberalism? It was, as Marx never tired of pointing out, to separate the
economic sphere from the political sphere and to confine politics to the latter
while leaving the economic sphere to capital. It is liberalism’s splendid
success in achieving this long-held goal that we are now observing. Take a look
at South Africa
today, more than two decades after Nelson Mandela was freed and the political
sphere, at long last, embraced the whole population. The ANC’s predicament was
that, in order to be allowed to dominate the political sphere, it had to give
up power over the economic one. And if you think otherwise, I suggest that you
talk to the dozens of miners gunned down by armed guards paid by their
employers after they dared demand a wage rise.
Why erratic?
Having explained why I owe whatever
understanding of our social world I may possess largely to Karl Marx, I now
want to explain why I remain terribly angry with him. In other words, I shall
outline why I am by choice an erratic, inconsistent Marxist. Marx committed two
spectacular mistakes, one of them an error of omission, the other one of
commission. Even today, these mistakes still hamper the left’s effectiveness,
especially in Europe .
Marx’s first error – the error of omission
was that he failed to give sufficient thought to the impact of his own
theorising on the world that he was theorising about. His theory is
discursively exceptionally powerful, and Marx had a sense of its power. So how
come he showed no concern that his disciples, people with a better grasp of
these powerful ideas than the average worker, might use the power bestowed upon
them, via Marx’s own ideas, in order to abuse other comrades, to build their
own power base, to gain positions of influence?
Marx’s second error, the one I ascribe to
commission, was worse. It was his assumption that truth about capitalism could be
discovered in the mathematics of his models. This was the worst disservice he
could have delivered to his own theoretical system. The man who equipped us
with human freedom as a first-order economic concept; the scholar who elevated
radical indeterminacy to its rightful place within political economics; he was
the same person who ended up toying around with simplistic algebraic models, in
which labour units were, naturally, fully quantified, hoping against hope to
evince from these equations some additional insights about capitalism. After
his death, Marxist economists wasted long careers indulging a similar type of
scholastic mechanism. Fully immersed in irrelevant debates on “the
transformation problem” and what to do about it, they eventually became an
almost extinct species, as the neoliberal juggernaut crushed all dissent in its
path.
How could Marx be so deluded? Why did he
not recognise that no truth about capitalism can ever spring out of any
mathematical model, however brilliant the modeller may be? Did he not have the
intellectual tools to realise that capitalist dynamics spring from the
unquantifiable part of human labour; ie from a variable that can never be
well-defined mathematically? Of course he did, since he forged these tools! No,
the reason for his error is a little more sinister: just like the vulgar
economists that he so brilliantly admonished (and who continue to dominate the
departments of economics today), he coveted the power that mathematical “proof”
afforded him.
“Why did Marx not recognise that no truth about
capitalism can ever spring out of any mathematical model?”
If I am right, Marx knew what he was doing.
He understood, or had the capacity to know, that a comprehensive theory of
value cannot be accommodated within a mathematical model of a dynamic
capitalist economy. He was, I have no doubt, aware that a proper economic
theory must respect the idea that the rules of the undetermined are themselves
undetermined. In economic terms this meant a recognition that the market power,
and thus the profitability, of capitalists was not necessarily reducible to
their capacity to extract labour from employees; that some capitalists can
extract more from a given pool of labour or from a given community of consumers
for reasons that are external to Marx’s own theory.
Alas, that recognition would be tantamount
to accepting that his “laws” were not immutable. He would have to concede to
competing voices in the trades union movement that his theory was indeterminate
and, therefore, that his pronouncements could not be uniquely and unambiguously
correct. That they were permanently provisional. This determination to have the
complete, closed story, or model, the final word, is something I cannot forgive
Marx for. It proved, after all, responsible for a great deal of error and, more
significantly, authoritarianism. Errors and authoritarianism that are largely
responsible for the left’s current impotence as a force of good and as a check
on the abuses of reason and liberty that the neoliberal crew are overseeing
today.
Mrs Thatcher’s lesson
I moved to England
to attend university in September 1978, six months or so before Margaret
Thatcher’s victory changed Britain
forever. Watching the Labour government disintegrate, under the weight of its
degenerate social democratic programme, led me to a serious error: to the
thought that Thatcher’s victory could be a good thing, delivering to Britain’s
working and middle classes the short, sharp shock necessary to reinvigorate
progressive politics; to give the left a chance to create a fresh, radical agenda
for a new type of effective, progressive politics.
Even as unemployment doubled and then
trebled, under Thatcher’s radical neoliberal interventions, I continued to
harbour hope that Lenin was right: “Things have to get worse before they get
better.” As life became nastier, more brutish and, for many, shorter, it
occurred to me that I was tragically in error: things could get worse in
perpetuity, without ever getting better. The hope that the deterioration of
public goods, the diminution of the lives of the majority, the spread of
deprivation to every corner of the land would, automatically, lead to a
renaissance of the left was just that: hope.
The reality was, however, painfully
different. With every turn of the recession’s screw, the left became more
introverted, less capable of producing a convincing progressive agenda and,
meanwhile, the working class was being divided between those who dropped out of
society and those co-opted into the neoliberal mindset. My hope that Thatcher
would inadvertently bring about a new political revolution was well and truly
bogus. All that sprang out of Thatcherism were extreme financialisation, the
triumph of the shopping mall over the corner store, the fetishisation of
housing and Tony Blair.
Margaret Thatcher at the Conservative party
conference in 1982. Photograph: Nils Jorgensen/Rex Features
|
Instead of radicalising British society,
the recession that Thatcher’s government so carefully engineered, as part of
its class war against organised labour and against the public institutions of
social security and redistribution that had been established after the war,
permanently destroyed the very possibility of radical, progressive politics in Britain .
Indeed, it rendered impossible the very notion of values that transcended what
the market determined as the “right” price.
The lesson Thatcher taught me about the
capacity of a long‑lasting recession to undermine
progressive politics, is one that I carry with me into today’s European crisis.
It is, indeed, the most important determinant of my stance in relation to the
crisis. It is the reason I am happy to confess to the sin I am accused of by
some of my critics on the left: the sin of choosing not to propose radical
political programs that seek to exploit the crisis as an opportunity to
overthrow European capitalism, to dismantle the awful eurozone, and to
undermine the European Union of the cartels and the bankrupt bankers.
Yes, I would love to put forward such a
radical agenda. But, no, I am not prepared to commit the same error twice. What
good did we achieve in Britain
in the early 1980s by promoting an agenda of socialist change that British
society scorned while falling headlong into Thatcher’s neoliberal trap?
Precisely none. What good will it do today to call for a dismantling of the
eurozone, of the European Union itself, when European capitalism is doing its
utmost to undermine the eurozone, the European Union, indeed itself?
A Greek or a Portuguese or an Italian exit
from the eurozone would soon lead to a fragmentation of European capitalism,
yielding a seriously recessionary surplus region east of the Rhine and north of
the Alps, while the rest of Europe is would be in the grip of vicious
stagflation. Who do you think would benefit from this development? A
progressive left, that will rise Phoenix-like from the ashes of Europe ’s public institutions? Or the Golden Dawn Nazis,
the assorted neofascists, the xenophobes and the spivs? I have absolutely no
doubt as to which of the two will do best from a disintegration of the
eurozone.
I, for one, am not prepared to blow fresh
wind into the sails of this postmodern version of the 1930s. If this means that
it is we, the suitably erratic Marxists, who must try to save European
capitalism from itself, so be it. Not out of love for European capitalism, for
the eurozone, for Brussels ,
or for the European Central Bank, but just because we want to minimise the
unnecessary human toll from this crisis.
What should Marxists do?
Yet with Europe ’s
elites deep in denial and disarray, the left must admit that we are just not
ready to plug the chasm that a collapse of European capitalism would open up
with a functioning socialist system. Our task should then be twofold. First, to
put forward an analysis of the current state of play that non-Marxist, well
meaning Europeans who have been lured by the sirens of neoliberalism, find
insightful. Second, to follow this sound analysis up with proposals for
stabilising Europe – for ending the downward
spiral that, in the end, reinforces only the bigots.
Let me now conclude with two confessions.
First, while I am happy to defend as genuinely radical the pursuit of a modest
agenda for stabilising a system that I criticise, I shall not pretend to be
enthusiastic about it. This may be what we must do, under the present
circumstances, but I am sad that I shall probably not be around to see a more
radical agenda being adopted.
“Europe’s elites are behaving as if they understand
neither the nature of the crisis, nor its implications for the future”
My final confession is of a highly personal
nature: I know that I run the risk of, surreptitiously, lessening the sadness
from ditching any hope of replacing capitalism in my lifetime by indulging a
feeling of having become agreeable to the circles of polite society. The sense
of self-satisfaction from being feted by the high and mighty did begin, on
occasion, to creep up on me. And what a non-radical, ugly, corruptive and
corrosive sense it was.
My personal nadir came at an airport. Some
moneyed outfit had invited me to give a keynote speech on the European crisis
and had forked out the ludicrous sum necessary to buy me a first-class ticket.
On my way back home, tired and with several flights under my belt, I was making
my way past the long queue of economy passengers, to get to my gate. Suddenly I
noticed, with horror, how easy it was for my mind to be infected with the sense
that I was entitled to bypass the hoi polloi. I realised how readily I could
forget that which my leftwing mind had always known: that nothing succeeds in
reproducing itself better than a false sense of entitlement. Forging alliances
with reactionary forces, as I think we should do to stabilise Europe today,
brings us up against the risk of becoming co-opted, of shedding our radicalism
through the warm glow of having “arrived” in the corridors of power.
Radical confessions, like the one I have
attempted here, are perhaps the only programmatic antidote to ideological
slippage that threatens to turn us into cogs of the machine. If we are to forge
alliances with our political adversaries we must avoid becoming like the
socialists who failed to change the world but succeeded in improving their
private circumstances. The trick is to avoid the revolutionary maximalism that,
in the end, helps the neoliberals bypass all opposition to their self-defeating
policies and to retain in our sights capitalism’s inherent failures while
trying to save it, for strategic purposes, from itself.
This article is adapted from a lecture
originally delivered at the 6th Subversive Festival in Zagreb in 2013
Sem comentários:
Enviar um comentário