Para todos aqueles que interpretam as origens da presente crise Económica de uma forma mais vasta, como uma crise civilizacional ... e se preocupam ansiosamente com a questão ecológica e com as consequências para a mesma, da ideia/conceito de Crescimento Económico progressivo/linear/Ilimitado ilustrado na presente escola positivista/materialista que dominou a Economia e que encontrou o seu ponto culminante auto-destruidor no Neo-Liberalismo ... este é um livro a ler .
Não tanto assim pelas possíveis soluções concretas que ofereçe ( nào o faz) mas pelo caminho de reflexão que ofereçe através da História sobre o presente vazio no pensamento económico no que respeita a Vida e a Cultura Humana/Civilização, e respectiva falácia sobre uma hipotética exactidão/controle/ segurança.
Este livro poderá de certa forma ser comparado na área Económica com outro que na área da História das Ideias e Teoria Arquitectónica, me impressionou fortemente, na minha qualidade de Historiador de Arquitectura: "Architecture and the Crisis of Modern Science" de Alberto Perez Gomez.
António Sérgio Rosa de Carvalho.
Economics of Good and Evil
Samuel Brittan Financial Times 25/06/11
Review of Economics of Good and Evil: The Quest for Economic
Meaning from Gilgamesh to Wall Street, by Tomas Sedlacek, Oxford University
Press, USA, RRP£16.99, 384 pages
It would be a great pity if potential readers of this book
were put off by the word "economics" in the title. Many people regard
the subject either as dry and technical or, worse, as an abject failure because
of the inability of its practitioners to anticipate the recent financial tsunami
and prescribe effectively for its aftermath. But Tomas Sedlacek's Economics of
Good and Evil, an unlikely bestseller when it was published in Czech in 2009,
is none of these things.
For Sedlacek economics is not - or at least not merely - a
science with its roots in the north-western fringes of Enlightenment Europe; it
stands, rather, at the heart of every philosophy and religion since the first
civilisations arose on the Mesopotamian delta. His book, accordingly, is
effectively a critical history of western thought. The author, a prominent
Czech commentator who was an adviser to Václav Havel when he was president,
uses the attitudes of various cultures towards getting and spending as a thread
on which to link his reflections. Moreover, unlike most books with large pretensions,
this one is beautifully written and at least for the first two-thirds I could
not put it down or turn my mind to anything else.
He starts off with The Epic of Gilgamesh, the oldest known
piece of literature, dating from around 2000BC. In the poem Gilgamesh is a
demi-god who rules from the city of Uruk in what is now Iraq. After numerous
adventures, immortality eludes him. "The end of the story," writes
Sedlacek, "returns to where the epic began - to the song in praise of
Uruk's wall". He takes this as a defining statement of a static view of
human destiny. There is much change and turbulence but no real progress.
"Time was cyclical and humanity was expected to make no historical
motion."
The author then turns to the Old Testament. "As opposed
to Christianity the concept of an extraterrestial paradise or heaven was not
much developed in Hebrew thought." This chapter is a crucial reminder for
those of us who were brought up in the Jewish tradition of ritual, prohibition
and painful word-for-word translation of sacred texts. For the author, the
important thing is the Jewish welcome for material progress, combined with a
very firm view of its limitations. Examples include not only the Sabbath but
also ideas such as a "year of rest" every seven years and a Jubilee
every 49th year, in which all debts were forgiven and land returned to its
original owner. It is a matter of speculation whether the Jubilee was ever
instituted in practice; I wish, even so, there had been some discussion of
whether there are equivalents in the modern world.
The discussion leads on naturally to Aristotle's eudaimonia,
often translated as "happiness" but in reality a much more
sophisticated concept than mere pleasure or the economist's notion of utility.
Aristotelian ideas of the good life stand in contrast to those of Plato, who
distrusted a material world that he regarded as in some sense unreal. Plato was
also a thorough-going egalitarian - not for the whole population but for the
chosen "guardians". He carried this idea to its logical conclusion by
ordaining that the children of guardians should be brought up communally rather
than in families.
This tension between the Platonic and Aristotelian views
continued in the Christian tradition. While the basic teaching was renunciation
in favour of the world to come, there were important nuances. Anyone curious
about the difference between Saints Augustine and Thomas Aquinas could do worse
than look at Sedlacek's account. While Augustine wanted to deny all bodily
pleasures, "Aquinas turns the pendulum and the material world gets
attention and care". The author even has an illuminating chart showing the
varying attitudes to the pursuit of pleasure: Kant is the most censorious while
satirist Bernard Mandeville stands at the opposite pole.
When it comes to later centuries Sedlacek, like many other
central European authors, disputes the prominence given in western political
economy to Adam Smith. (Incidentally, he rightly insists, contrary to most
Anglo-Saxon critics, that there is a tension between the espousal of
self-interest in The Wealth of Nations and the espousal of benevolence in the
same author's Theory of Moral Sentiments.) He has no difficulty in showing the
two basic ideas of the division of labour and the invisible hand were
formulated long before. Indeed, some of them go back to the ancient Greek
writer, Xenophon.
The author has some difficulty in sorting out the difference
between Mandeville's view that it is pleasure that makes the world go round and
that of Smith, who denounced Mandeville as severely as any contemporary
prelate. The difference surely is that Mandeville was a proto-Keynesian who saw
that if we all saved and never spent economic society would come to an end,
while Smith merely wanted to harness self-interest to the common good.
What moral does Sedlacek draw from this long, but
necessarily abbreviated, history? Here is where disappointment begins. He has
two conclusions. One is the inadequacy of contemporary mechanistic econometric
models to interpret the world or to give on their own useful advice. The other
is a stricture on the obsession with economic growth. The criticism is not that
his conclusions are wrong but that he does little to persuade the reader who
does not already agree with him. Sedlacek's preoccupation with the evils of
official debt can make him sound like a publicist for the European Central Bank
or the International Monetary Fund. His one practical proposal, that of
mandatory budget surpluses for countries whose annual growth exceeds 3 per cent
offset by deficits when growth is less, is not a bad one in a European or US
context, but would hardly do for a country such as China.
As for the limitations of the current mainstream economic
approach, the author, who has advised banks as well as presidents, had a golden
opportunity to demonstrate this from recent experience. Instead he is content
with an a priori broadside. On a more philosophical plane, I wish he would do a
little more to honour the promise of his title and analyse the concepts of good
and evil - on which both Thomas Hobbes and David Hume, who figure prominently
here, had much to say. Nevertheless, for anyone whose range of interest extends
beyond the latest twist in the Greek debt crisis or the possibility of a
double-dip recession the book is still a compulsive read, from which we have to
draw our own conclusions.
Sem comentários:
Enviar um comentário