A global debt crisis is looming – how can we
prevent it?
There is an urgent need for wide-ranging debt relief
in the midst of the coronavirus pandemic
The views expressed here are the authors’ own and do not reflect the views of the United Nations or its member states.
Joseph
Stiglitz and Hamid Rashid
Mon 3 Aug
2020 07.00 BSTLast modified on Mon 3 Aug 2020 07.02 BST
https://www.theguardian.com/business/2020/aug/03/global-debt-crisis-relief-coronavirus-pandemic
While the
Covid-19 pandemic rages, more than 100 low- and middle-income countries will
still have to pay a combined $130bn in debt service this year – around half of
which is owed to private creditors. With much economic activity suspended and
fiscal revenues in free fall, many countries will be forced to default. Others
will cobble together scarce resources to pay creditors, cutting back on
much-needed health and social expenditures. Still others will resort to
additional borrowing, kicking the proverbial can down the road, seemingly
easier now because of the flood of liquidity from central banks around the
world.
From Latin
America’s lost decade in the 1980s to the more recent Greek crisis, there are
plenty of painful reminders of what happens when countries cannot service their
debts. A global debt crisis today will push millions of people into
unemployment and fuel instability and violence around the world. Many will seek
jobs abroad, potentially overwhelming border-control and immigration systems in
Europe and North America. Another costly migration crisis will divert attention
away from the urgent need to address climate change. Such humanitarian
emergencies are becoming the new norm.
This
nightmare scenario is avoidable if we act now. The origins of today’s looming
debt crisis are easy to understand. Owing to quantitative easing, the public
debt (mostly sovereign bonds) of low- and middle-income countries has more than
tripled since the 2008 global financial crisis. Sovereign bonds are riskier
than “official” debt from multilateral institutions and developed-country aid
agencies because creditors can dump them on a whim, triggering a sharp currency
depreciation and other far-reaching economic disruptions.
Back in
June 2013, we worried that “shortsighted financial markets, working with
shortsighted governments,” were “laying the groundwork for the world’s next
debt crisis.” Now, the day of reckoning has come. This past March, the United
Nations called for debt relief for the world’s least-developed countries.
Several G20 countries and the International Monetary Fund have suspended debt
service for the year, and have called upon private creditors to follow suit.
Unsurprisingly,
these calls have fallen on deaf ears. The newly formed Africa Private Creditor
Working Group, for example, has already rejected the idea of modest but
broad-based debt relief for poor countries. As a result, much, if not most, of
the benefits of debt relief from official creditors will accrue to the private
creditors who are unwilling to provide any debt relief.
The upshot
is that taxpayers in creditor countries will once again end up bailing out
excessive risk taking and imprudent lending by private actors. The only way to
avoid this is to have a comprehensive debt standstill that includes private
creditors. But without strong action from the countries in which debt contracts
are written, private creditors are unlikely to accept such an arrangement.
These governments therefore must invoke the doctrines of necessity and force
majeure to enforce comprehensive standstills on debt service.
But
standstills will not solve the systemic problem of excessive indebtedness. For
that, we urgently need deep debt restructuring. History shows that for many
countries, a restructuring that is too little, too late merely sets the stage
for another crisis. And Argentina’s long struggle to restructure its debt in
the face of recalcitrant, shortsighted, hard-headed, and hard-hearted private
creditors has shown that collective-action clauses designed to facilitate
restructuring are not as effective as had been hoped.
More often
than not, an inadequate restructuring is followed by another restructuring
within five years, with enormous suffering on the part of those in the debtor
country. Even creditors lose, over the long run.
Fortunately,
there is an underused alternative: voluntary sovereign-debt buybacks. Debt
buybacks are widespread in the corporate world, and have proved effective both
in Latin America in the 1990s and, more recently, in the Greek context. And
they have the advantage of avoiding the harsh terms that typically come with
debt swaps.
A buyback
program’s principal objective would be to reduce debt burdens by securing
significant discounts (haircuts) on the face value of sovereign bonds, and by
minimising exposure to risky private creditors. But a buyback program could
also be designed to advance health and climate goals, by requiring that the
beneficiaries spend the money that otherwise would have gone to debt service on
creating public goods.
As we
explain in a recent proposal, a multilateral buyback facility could be managed
by the IMF, which can use already available resources, its New Arrangements to
Borrow function, and supplemental funds from a global consortium of countries
and multilateral institutions. Countries that do not need their full allocation
of special drawing rights, the IMF’s unit of account, could donate or lend them
to the new facility. A new issuance of SDRs, for which there is a clear need,
could provide still additional resources. To ensure the maximum debt reduction
for a given expenditure, the IMF could conduct an auction, announcing that it
will buy back only a limited amount of bonds.
In the long
term, a predictable, rules-based debt-restructuring mechanism, modelled after
the US municipal bankruptcy legislation (“Chapter 9”) is needed. That would be
in keeping with the recommendations of the post-2008 UN Commission of Experts
on Reforms of the International Monetary and Financial System.
The usual
objection to such proposals is that they would destroy the international
capital market. But experience shows otherwise. One can’t squeeze water from a
stone. There will be restructuring – the only question is whether it will be
orderly. Our proposals would aid in achieving this objective, and thus
strengthen capital markets.
Ultimately,
though, our concern should not be with the health of capital markets, but with
the welfare of people in developing and emerging-market countries. There is an
urgent need for debt relief now, in the midst of the pandemic. It has to be
comprehensive – including private creditors – and more than just a stay of
debt. We have the tools to do it. We only need the political will.
The views
expressed here are the authors’ own and do not reflect the views of the United
Nations or its member states.
• Joseph E
Stiglitz is a Nobel laureate in economics, university professor at Columbia
University and chief economist at the Roosevelt Institute.
• Hamid Rashid, a former director-general for multilateral economic affairs at the Ministry of Foreign Affairs in Bangladesh and senior adviser at the UNDP’s Bureau for Development Policy, is chief of global economic monitoring at the United N
Sem comentários:
Enviar um comentário