The 'market' won't save us from climate disaster.
We must rethink our system
Expecting the free market to fix global warming is
like trying to pound nails with a saw
Robert S
Devine
Thu 19 Nov
2020 11.30 GMTLast modified on Thu 19 Nov 2020 11.46 GMT
https://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2020/nov/19/climate-crisis-markets-economic-system
Nicholas
Stern, the former chief economist of the World Bank, calls climate change the
‘greatest and widest-ranging market failure ever seen.’
The massive
wildfires that have been rampaging across the American west this year are not
purely natural disasters. They are partly products of the unnatural disaster of
climate change – “unnatural”, in that the ultimate responsibility for global
warming belongs not to physics but to our economic system. Nicholas Stern, the
former chief economist of the World Bank, calls climate change the “greatest
and widest-ranging market failure ever seen”. Sadly, climate change is only one
– albeit a whopper – of the countless market failures that degrade our lives.
Though it
sounds like a generic phrase, “market failure” is actually a technical term. It
doesn’t refer to scams like insider trading or corporate fraud. A failure
occurs when the marketplace allocates resources in a way that does not
optimally deliver wellbeing. We understandably focus a lot of attention on the
depredations of greedy tycoons and corporations, but many of the most
consequential market failures stem from innate characteristics of our current
market system.
Many of us
probably already have a gut feeling that our current market system often fails.
In order to build a more sustainable, just and prosperous economy, however,
it’s vital that we better comprehend the shortcomings deep in the market’s DNA.
Greater awareness would reduce blind faith in the market and enable people to
see the market for what it is: a tool. It can be an excellent tool when used for
the right job, but relying on the market to deal with something like climate
change is like trying to pound nails with a saw.
One major
inherent flaw involves communication. In an ideal version of the market,
continuous indirect communication between consumers and producers leads to the
best allocation of society’s resources. Consumers make their desires known by
the prices they’re willing to pay, and producers convey their costs by the
prices they charge.
However,
producers only communicate a narrow range of costs. For example, an oil company
will account for typical expenses, like payments to its employees, and then set
its prices accordingly. Consumers will receive those price signals and decide
whether to buy that company’s gasoline. But markets enable businesses to scrub
most social and environmental costs from these signals, which garbles
communication with consumers. For instance, the price of gas doesn’t reflect
the cost of the revved-up wildfires we suffer due to the additional global
warming caused by burning that oil company’s gasoline. Numerous studies
estimate that the true cost of gas is two to four times higher than what we pay
at the pump.
Incomplete
communication misleads us consumers into buying products laden with hidden costs.
Countless goods and services bear the stains of harms such as pollution,
habitat destruction, floods, child labor, extinctions and disease. When we fill
up at the gas station the price we are charged doesn’t tell us that our
purchase increases the odds that a wildfire will burn down our community.
Making such partially informed choices is like buying a house having seen only
the kitchen.
Another
characteristic of the market that leads to failure is its inability to provide
incentives for businesses to produce or protect public goods, such as fire
departments or city parks. Most important, the market doesn’t generate the
public goods sometimes known as “ecosystem services”, such as nutrient cycling,
soil formation, oxygen creation and a livable climate. Many of these essential
services operate in the background; like plumbing and wiring, they go unnoticed
and unappreciated unless they fail.
Purposeful collective action is the
overarching solution to market failures
Take the
flooding that drowned parts of coastal Louisiana and Mississippi in 2005 when
Hurricane Katrina thrashed the Gulf coast. More than 1,800 people died,
cherished communities disintegrated, and the price tag swelled to more than
$100bn. Much of the devastation occurred because oil and gas development had
decimated the coastal marshes that previously had tamed storm surges. The
protection those marshes provide is an extremely valuable ecosystem service,
yet no entrepreneurs hustle to produce that protection.
And why
would they? The market doesn’t give private businesses a profit motive to
produce public goods. For example, even if a company were to restore a marsh,
they wouldn’t be able to sell that service because they couldn’t exclude anyone
living on that coast from using that protection for free.
Private
restoration companies exist, of course, and some make a profit by
rehabilitating marshes. But market forces didn’t spawn these outfits. At some
point somebody recognized the value of the marshes and made a conscious choice
to try to preserve or restore them. Most likely a number of somebodies made
that choice and pressed their government to hire a restoration company. More
broadly, environmental and social projects happen when a great many somebodies
vote for candidates who support such efforts. Such purposeful collective action
is the overarching solution to market failures. Instead of passively counting
on supply and demand to provide everything we need, we sometimes need to exert
our judgment.
And there
it is, the J-word: “judgment”. Free-enterprise disciples view most efforts to
use our collective judgment to shape the economy as central planning that will
foul the gears of the market. But banishing judgment about how to allocate our
resources will result in a world with plenty of video game consoles and
fashionable shoes and precious little biodiversity and climate stability – and,
all too soon, biological poverty and climate chaos will also cripple the
economy of stuff, and video game consoles and shoes will become scarce, as
well.
Citizens
who scorn judgment should note that we’ve exercised some collective judgment to
help guide the economy since the advent of government. The problem is that
we’re not exercising it enough. In recent decades we’ve gotten out of balance
and are leaning too far toward an unrestrained market even when it’s the wrong
tool for the job.
Consider
your toaster. It’s loaded with hidden costs that the market doesn’t communicate
and that individual consumers can’t be expected to discover. But government
(well, good government that pays attention to science) has the expertise to
evaluate your toaster. If we citizens decide that we want to address climate
change and air pollution, then government can do our bidding by devising energy
efficiency standards for our appliances.
In fact,
they did, decades ago. According to the American Council for an
Energy-Efficient Economy, those regulations have saved more than $1tn to date
and have reduced greenhouse gas emissions by the equivalent of the annual
emissions of 800m cars. And we don’t even know the standards are there – hardly
the heavy hand of government that haunts free-marketeers’ fever dreams.
So let’s
use our judgment to create an economy that better aligns with our values.
Instead of surrendering our autonomy to the soulless mechanics of the market,
we can freely choose to grow beyond being mere consumers and become forceful
citizens.
Robert S
Devine is the author of Bush Versus the Environment and The Sustainable
Economy: The Hidden Costs of Climate Change and the Path to a Prosperous Future
Sem comentários:
Enviar um comentário