Opinion
Guest Essay
Trump Is
About to Bet the Economy on a Theory That Makes No Sense
March 31,
2025
By Jason
Furman
https://www.nytimes.com/2025/03/31/opinion/trump-tariffs-economy.html
Dr. Furman,
a contributing Opinion writer, is a professor of the practice of economic
policy at Harvard University and was chairman of the White House Council of
Economic Advisers from 2013 to 17.
My local
bookstore has been taking advantage of me for years. I have run a trade
deficit, giving it money with nothing but books in return. At the same time I
have been taking advantage of my employer, running a trade surplus with it as
it gives me a salary with nothing but educational services in exchange.
Thinking
that way about the kinds of exchanges we all engage in is obviously absurd. But
that’s precisely the reasoning behind the “reciprocal tariffs” President Trump
is expected to announce this week. The details have not yet come into view, but
if he does follow through, it’s clear the plan would add to what are already
the nation’s highest tariffs since the 1940s. Their effect will be lower
economic growth, higher inflation, higher unemployment, the destruction of
wealth and a tax increase on American families. It will deal a blow to the
rules underlying the global trading system and further empower China.
Mr. Trump
has cycled through numerous rationales for tariffs: They will raise revenues,
with foreigners footing the bill. They will help American manufacturers and
national security. They will provide leverage against Mexican fentanyl and
Canadian sovereignty. In all of these cases there is a bit of truth and a lot
of falsehood.
But the one
argument Mr. Trump has returned to again and again is that other countries are
taking advantage of the United States. He measures the degree to which they are
doing so by the magnitude of our trade deficit with them — that is, how much
more money we spend on another country’s goods and services than we get from
selling it our goods and services.
In this
reckoning, the reason those deficits arise is that other countries erect
tariffs and other trade barriers against the United States. It follows from
this analysis that the solution is to reciprocate by erecting our own tariffs,
which will either protect the United States or else get other countries to
lower their barriers, either way reducing or eliminating the trade deficits.
Every step
in this chain of reasoning is wrong.
Start with
the fact that imports are good, not bad. They offer consumers greater variety,
such as avocados from Mexico, lower prices on cars from South Korea or greater
quality, including Champagne from France. American companies are able to offer
better products at lower prices and be globally competitive because they use
imported steel, auto parts and precision machinery. Moreover, importing these
items frees us up to devote more of our production and employment to higher
productivity and higher-wage jobs, including in export industries such as
aerospace and software design.
Running
bilateral trade deficits is generally not an indication of a problem or an
abuse. In recent years the United States exported more to Brazil than it
imported, a fact that had more to do with Brazil’s appetite for American oil
and airplanes than any trade barriers. In fact, Brazil levies an average tariff
of 6 percent on goods coming from the United States, well in excess of the 1
percent levied by the United States on imports from Brazil. Same in reverse for
the United States and France: We import more than we export despite having a
higher tariff on their goods than they do on ours.
In fact,
there is generally no correlation between a country’s tariff levels and its
overall trade balance. A particularly clear example is the 27 countries in the
European Union, which have identical tariffs and other trade policies but range
from trade deficits to trade surpluses.
So if
tariffs don’t create trade deficits, what does? The answer has to do with
whether a country saves its money or invests it, in things like factories,
infrastructure and research. The United States invests more than it saves,
which has helped fuel our enviable productivity and growth. To fill the gap, we
attract money from overseas. Foreign investors exchange their euros, yen and
yuan for dollars to invest in the United States. We can then use those euros,
yen and yuan to buy more of what we want from Europe, Japan and China than we
sell them. Voilà, a deficit.
What then
will these reciprocal tariffs do? They will lessen the overall volume of trade.
The United States will import less because foreign goods and services will
become more expensive. It will also export less, because the tariffs that other
countries erect against us will make our stuff more expensive for them.
Even if
other countries don’t retaliate against our tariffs with a slew of their own,
the situation is still bad. Take automobile tariffs on Mexico. They would cause
Americans to buy fewer cars from that country, so we would need fewer pesos,
the things with which you buy their cars. As demand for Mexican currency goes
down, so does its value relative to the dollar. But a strong dollar makes it
more expensive for foreign countries to buy our exports. Either way, less
trade, which would be bad for both consumers and workers. (As an aside, if the
tariffs do succeed in meaningfully lowering trade deficits it would most likely
be because they caused a recession, bringing down the amount U.S. consumers buy
or businesses invest.)
If all
reciprocal tariffs are bad in theory, however, Mr. Trump’s seem likely to be
even worse in practice. That’s because he’s not just looking to even things out
with other countries by raising U.S. tariffs by a percentage point or two, the
current difference in tariff rates between the United States and many of its
trade partners. Instead, he has been cherry-picking examples of goods where
other countries have higher tariffs than the United States while ignoring the
many cases where the reverse is true.
The
president even claimed that foreign value-added taxes, or VATs, discriminate
against American exports. It is true that these VATs apply to American goods,
from oranges to cars to cosmetics. But they apply in equal measure to European
oranges and cars and cosmetics. They don’t discriminate against the United
States or any other country. And demanding that European countries change them
would mean demanding that they alter core aspects of their tax systems. Why
would they ever agree?
The
consequences of this are serious. In Mr. Trump’s first term he raised average
tariffs by about 1.5 percentage points. With all of the trade measures he has
already carried out this year, they have gone up another six percentage points
— and reciprocal tariffs could add much more. All told, the tariff increases in
the first four months of his latest trade war are likely to be five to 10 times
as large as those he imposed in the four years of his first term.
There’s been
a lot of talk about whether that will crash the economy altogether. The
enormous increase in business uncertainty that tariffs have engendered means
anything could happen. Goldman Sachs, however, estimates that given this new
round of tariffs, economic growth will decline by about 0.5 percentage point
(largely because imported goods are only one-tenth of U.S. gross domestic
product). Not a huge number on its own, though it translates to about $1,000
per household but it would push up inflation by a similar magnitude. All of
this is on top of the harm done by all the tariffs that have already been
announced.
Lower-income
families will pay a higher fraction of their income in tariffs, but the revenue
will very likely go to tax cuts skewed to high-income households. The stock
market has already lost more than $3 trillion since Mr. Trump first dialed up
his tariff threats in February. The losses could grow over time as the United
States increasingly distances itself from the benefits of imports, exports and
global supply chains.
The
geopolitical realignment this will help engender may be even more profound. The
United States has leverage vis-à-vis Canada and Mexico because we are their
main trade partner. But China is the largest trading partner for a majority of
countries in the world. Give these countries a choice between economic
relations with the United States and with China, they would probably choose the
latter in a heartbeat. And where economic relations go, political relations
will follow. This week’s tariffs are another step toward hurting the U.S.
economy and creating a geopolitical system that increasingly has China at its
center.
Jason
Furman, a contributing Opinion writer, is a professor of the practice of
economic policy at Harvard University and was chairman of the White House
Council of Economic Advisers from 2013 to 2017.
Sem comentários:
Enviar um comentário